Tuesday, September 25, 2012

Confucius: The Economist?

Compare the Analects 2.3...
The Master said: Guide them with policies and align them with punishments and the people will evade them and have no shame. Guide them with virtue (de) and align them with li and the people will have a sense of shame and fulfill their roles.

...with the daycare experiment made famous by Freakonomics:
Imagine for a moment that you are the manager of a day-care center. You have a clearly stated policy that children are supposed to be picked up by 4 P.M. But very often parents are late. The result: at day's end, you have some anxious children and at least one teacher who must wait around for the parents to arrive. What to do? 
A pair of economists who heard of this dilemma... offered a solution: fine the tardy parents... The economists decided to test their solution by conducting a study of ten day-care centers in Haifa, Israel. The study lasted twenty weeks, but the fine was not introduced immediately. For the first four weeks, the economists simply kept track of the number of parents who came late; there were, on average, eight late pickups per week per day-care center. In the fifth week, the fine was enacted. It was announced that any parent arriving more than ten minutes late would pay $3 per child for each incident. The fee would be added to the parents' monthly bill, which was roughly $380. 
After the fine was enacted, the number of late pickups promptly went . . . up. Before long there were twenty late pickups per week, more than double the original average. The incentive had plainly backfired.

Monday, September 10, 2012

The Microeconomics of Child Support

I was recently fortunate enough to do some work experience for a judge. As well as seeing some of the dramatic debates that one imagines taking place in court, I saw some of the smaller scale judgments that are made at tribunals. Primarily these were in relation to child support; either a parent with custody appealing that the specified level of child support was too low, or a parent without custody appealing that the specified level of custody was too high. In the cases that I saw all the parents with custody were mothers.

The first thing that struck me was the extent to which fathers went out of their way to avoid paying child support. Of course, this was clearly partially a result of the selection effect; the people at the tribunal were the select few trying to avoid paying. Nevertheless, there was an example of a mother suing a deceased father's estate for unpaid child support; their daughter was not a beneficiary of the estate at all. Surely, however much parents may come to hate each other, they would not go so far as to prevent their children from receiving money after their death?

However, once I thought about it, I realised that they might reasonably see child support going not primarily to their child but to their ex-spouse. Consider an imaginary example in which a father is ordered to pay £200 weekly to a mother with custody. It is essentially a transfer from the father to the mother to compensate her for the child's expense. One might reasonably expect that the mother will spend some of the money on the child, but it seems unlikely that it will be spent exclusively on the child. To think of it in another way, if the mother was made £200 poorer she would not reduce spending on the child by £200; she would seek to cushion the drop in income by reducing some of her own expenses. In fact, it seems likely that, given that in most cases the mother will already have bought the child the things which she deems necessary for their happiness, a significant portion of the money will essentially recompense her for this expense rather than be used for additional spending on the child.

Now, it is quite likely that the child support will not pay for half of the costs of bringing up the child (especially if one values the mother's time, too). As a transfer, it seems more than fair. Nevertheless, from the perspective of a father who hates the mother, one can see why he might be reluctant to pay child support even if they wish their child well. This doesn't excuse their behaviour, but it does begin to better explain some of it.

The Economics of Elections

In his latest New York Times column, Paul Krugman alleges that the Republican party has been deliberately obstructing measures that might help the American economy. I don't know enough about Republican strategy to be able to guess whether or not this is true, but if it were it would make excellent tactical sense.

As Ezra Klein of the Washington Post points out, incumbent politicians in growing economies almost always win elections. Incumbency and whether or not the economy is growing are by far the two most important factors that determine elections. The Republicans did their best to prevent the former in 2008. In 2012, the only one which they have any control over is the latter, the economy. Add to this calculus the fact that most measures that boost the economy significantly today have some future cost, and it becomes easier to understand why an anti-growth strategy could feel justified.

Tuesday, September 4, 2012

Leaving the Eurozone

Much speculation has gone on about countries leaving the euro. Having their own currency would be of immense advantage to struggling European countries like Spain and Greece, insofar as they could use monetary policy to attempt to revitalize their economies. On the other hand, these countries are exactly the ones which can least afford to bear the costs of abandoning the euro. The issue's urgency was recently highlighted by the revelation that some companies are making very specific preparations for a Greek exit.

In response to this, some have suggested that it may be Germany that exits the euro. It can better afford the associated cost (even just printing the appropriate quantity of paper money is a logistical nightmare), and this would cause less trauma to the weaker economies than in a scenario where one or many of them exited. However, such speculation misses an important point, beyond the political implausibility of this suggestion.

Germany has no need of its own currency - it has already got one, and it's called the euro. As Evan Soltas points out, the German economy is a decisive factor in the European Central Bank's policy making, getting twice as much consideration as the size of its economy would intuitively suggest.

Was China's Stimulus Worth It?

Tyler Cowen of Marginal Revolution forwards a challenge:
[Nick] emails me:
I have greatly enjoyed the recent pieces on China as I currently live in REDACTED…Fwiw, my take is that yes, the 2009 Chinese stimulus was a great test of large-scale govt stimulus and that we are seeing the results of what this looks like *in practice* rather than *in theory*. In practice, large-scale government stimulus is an invitation for corruption and a diversion of resources that builds up knowledge and capital in unproductive areas. As Obama said after the US stimulus package: there’s “no such thing as shovel ready projects.” Even in China.

Matt Yglesias at Slate responds:
But look at the numbers. In 2007, China's PPP-adjusted GDP per capita was $5,562. In 2008 it was $6,201. In 2009 it was $6,810. In 2010 it was $7,571. In 2011 it was $8,407. The 2012 growth numbers look certain to show a drastic slowing down of growth. But let's get really pessimistic about China and assume 0% growth across 2012 followed by a five percent contraction in real GDP per capita in 2013. That would still leave China's per capita GDP level about 50 percent higher than it was when the world starting going into recession. That seems to me like an enormous success story.
The big knock on the Chinese economy is that there's all this malinvestment and tons of white elephant projects. And perhaps there are. But there's no sector of the economy with lower productivity than the unemployment sector, and no public investment more wasteful than having a human being spend years scanning help wanted ads and feeling depressed. Does someone seriously want to argue that none of these projects have any value? It doesn't seem to me that anyone in China is debating whether or not the typical household is better off than it was four years ago. Here in the USA we've had about 2 to 3 percent of our workforce persistently engaged in doing nothing for the past several years, and the forecasts all show that trend continuing for a while. That, to me, looks like intolerable waste.

Sunday, September 2, 2012

High Impact Investment

If you want to support a charity, should you invest the money so that your donation grows in size before it is given? The typical answer is no; helping a charity immediately will usually have a future 'return' in the form of its beneficial impact at least comparable to any pecuniary return on your investment. Perhaps you've decided that investment is worthwhile, however - maybe you're a budding Warren Buffet.

How should you invest your money to maximise your altruistic impact in the future?

Risk Averse Investors

Most people are risk averse. To see this, we need only look at insurance, an example of people paying money to reduce the risk of extremely bad outcomes. If somebody insures their house against fire, they will pay more money on average than they will receive on average in insurance if their house is burnt down. Insurance companies are after profits; if they are paying out (to recompense those whose houses are burnt down) more than they are taking in (from everybody insuring against fire) then they will stop offering fire insurance. Assuming that insurance is a zero sum game, this means that people taking out fire insurance cannot be making money out of it on average.

So on average, fire insurance is not a good bet if all you are interested in is maximising your average bank account balance. However, most people quite reasonably care more about preserving a minimum bank account balance than maximising its average, so they are happy to buy fire insurance. A similar rationale can be applied to investment. Investors pay risk premia to avoid risk. This is why safe assets like gilts have lower returns than more risky assets.

In microeconomic theory, the standard explanation for this is that investors have a diminishing marginal utility of money1. Whether or not you consider this explanation valid, being more tolerant of risk in your investment will clearly earn you a better return. If you care more about saving more lives on average than you do about guaranteeing that a certain number of lives will be saved, it may be worth taking riskier investments. There are fewer diminishing marginal returns to charitable donations; so long as people are in areas at high risk of malaria, purchasing bed nets at a rate of $5 will be worth doing.


1. To illustrate this, imagine somebody who has no money (and no other possessions). We'll call them Max, since that happens to be my name and I've got very little money! There are a lot of things that I want to buy, but can't. I am more eager to buy some things than others, however; a car may seem attractive, but if you gave me £20,000 I would be more likely to spend it on a place to sleep than a car. Simplifying for the purpose of example, imagine that cars and cheap flats both cost £20,000. If I am given £20,000 I will buy a flat, increasing my welfare by a certain amount. If I am given another £20,000 I will buy a car, increasing my welfare again. This second increase must be less than the first because I wanted a flat more than I wanted a car. Therefore the second £20,000 is of less value to me than the first. Therefore there is a diminishing value to each unit of money that I am given. This is the diminishing marginal utility of money.